Rational Riddles: Unpacking the Puzzle of Political Polarization

Political Division

Kevin Dorst’s research on U.S. political polarization suggests that rationality plays a key role in forming diverse political opinions. His concept of ‘rational polarization’ posits that people interpret ambiguous political information differently, leading to varied conclusions. This challenges the notion that political beliefs are solely based on emotion or misinformation.

A study by philosopher Kevin Dorst explains how political differences can result from a process of “rational polarization.”

U.S. politics is heavily polarized. This is often regarded as a product of irrationality: People can be tribal, are influenced by their peers, and often get information from very different, sometimes inaccurate sources.

Tribalism and misinformation are real enough. But what if people are often acting rationally as well, even in the process of arriving at very different views? What if they are not being misled or too emotional, but are thinking logically?

Rational Polarization in Political Views

“There can be quite reasonable ways people can be predictably polarized,” says MIT philosopher Kevin Dorst, author of a new paper on the subject, based partly on his own empirical research.

This may especially be the case when people deal with a lot of ambiguity when weighing political and civic issues. Those ambiguities generate political asymmetry. People consider evidence in predictably different ways, leading them to different conclusions. That doesn’t mean they are not thinking logically, though.

Reasonable People Disagree

In a new paper, MIT professor of philosophy Kevin Dorst explores how people might rationally come to hold very different views about some political matters. Credit: Jose-Luis Olivares, MIT

“What’s going is people are selectively scrutinizing information,” Dorst says. “That’s effectively why they move in opposite directions, because they scrutinize and selectively look for flaws in different places, and so they get overall different takes.”

The concept of rational polarization may help us develop a more coherent account about how views differ, by helping us avoid thinking that we alone are rational — or, conversely, that we have done no real thinking while arriving at our own opinions. Thus it can add nuance to our assessments of others.

The paper, “Rational Polarization,” appears in The Philosophical Review. Dorst, the sole author, is an assistant professor in MIT’s Department of Linguistics and Philosophy.

Challenging Belief Formation Models

To Dorst, rational polarization stands as a useful alternative to other models about belief formation. In particular, rational polarization in his view improves upon one type of model of “Bayesian” thinking, in which people keep using new information to hone their views.

In Bayesian terms, because people use new information to update their views, they will rationally either change their ideas or not, as is warranted. it, But in reality, Dorst asserts, things are not so simple. Often when we assess new evidence, there is ambiguity present — and Dorst contends that it is rational to be unsure about that ambiguity. But this can generate polarization because people’s prior assumptions do influence the places where they find ambiguity.

Suppose a group of people have been given two studies about the death penalty: One study finds the death penalty has no deterrent effect on people’s behavior, and the other study finds it does. Even reading the same evidence, people in the group will likely wind up with different interpretations of it.

“Those who really believe in the deterrent effect will look closely at the study suggesting there is no deterrent effect, be skeptical about it, poke holes in the argument, and claim to recognize flaws in its reasoning,” Dorst says. “Conversely, for the people who disbelieve the deterrent effect, it’s the exact opposite. They find flaws in the study suggesting there is a deterrent effect.”

Even to these seemingly selective readings can be rational, Dorst says: “It makes sense to scrutinize surprising information more than unsurprising information.” Therefore, he adds, “You can see that people who have this tendency to selectively scrutinize [can] drift apart even when they are presented with the same evidence that’s mixed in the same way.”

Online Experiment Illustrating Ambiguity’s Role

To help show that this habit exists, Dorst also ran an online experiment about ambiguity, with 250 participants on the Prolific online survey platform. The aim was to see how much people’s views might become polarized in the presence of ambiguous information.

The participants were given an incomplete string of letters, as one might find in a crossword puzzle or on “Wheel of Fortune.” Some letter strings were parts of real words, and some were not. Depending on what kinds of additional information participants were given, the ambiguous, unsolvable strings of letters had a sharply polarizing effect on how people reacted to the additional information they received.

This process at work in the experiment, Dorst says, is similar to what happens when people receive uncertain information, in the news or in studies, about political matters.

“When you find a flaw, it gives you clear evidence that undermines the study,” Dorst says. Otherwise, people often tend to be uncertain about the material they see. “When you don’t find a flaw, it [can] give you ambiguous evidence and you don’t know what to make of it. As a result, that can lead to predictable polarization.”

The larger point, Dorst believes, is that we can arrive at a more nuanced and consistent picture of how political differences exist when people process similar information.

Rethinking Rationality in Politics

“There’s a perception that in politics, rational brains shut off and people think with their guts,” Dorst says. “If you take that seriously, you should say, ‘I form my beliefs on politics in the same ways.’”

Unless, that is, you believe you alone are rational, and everyone else is not — though Dorst finds this to be an untenable view of the world.

“Part of what I’m trying to do is give an account that’s not subject to that sort of instability,” Dorst says. “You don’t necessarily have to point the finger at others. It’s a much more interesting process if you think there’s something [rational] there as well.”

Reference: “Rational Polarization” by Kevin Dorst, 1 July 2023, The Philosophical Review.
DOI: 10.1215/00318108-10469499

2 Comments on "Rational Riddles: Unpacking the Puzzle of Political Polarization"

  1. Hottan Oscillating | December 28, 2023 at 10:03 am | Reply

    It’s nice to see philosophy news.

    Psychology has found humans are inherently irrational, but philosophy is concerned with studying rationality. With a scientific worldview, critical thinking can help people learn to rationally undermine studies which they would agree with. For example, in the past, my mind has been changed by a cavalcade of really bad studies in favor of positions I originally agreed with; this article’s answers wouldn’t predict that. That in itself may seem irrational, but when presented with consistently agreeable bad evidence, it’s rational to seek alternative explanations.

    I think the polarization stems less from many uncertain studies, and more from a vicious cycle of failure. As available options are chosen and fail, and the problems get worse, people seek increasingly divergent options. When the available options have all failed, the danger in politics becomes the necessity of people seeking politically-unavailable extreme options. The graphics here show red versus blue; what must you do when choosing either is a terrible mistake?

Leave a comment

Email address is optional. If provided, your email will not be published or shared.